Search This Blog

Saturday 10 August 2019

AUTHORITARIAN RULE IN THE MIDDLE EAST: WHY HAS IT PROVEN RESISTANT TO THE SPREAD OF DEMOCRACY

           Introduction
In broaching the leitmotifs of democracy and authoritarianism particularly in the Middle East Region of the globe, the endemic nature of various forms of unrest and upheavals raging from boarder/territory disputes, the politics of water, violence within the parameters of religion inter alia cannot be overemphasized and this can be partly attributed to the authoritarian regimes which has manned the helms of affairs of the region, thereby making the discourse of democracy look like a mirage; with the various instances of cases of human rights violation, issues of gender inequality and so on, which are the consequences of the region not being democratic.
The argument here is that, since various mechanisms and systems has been tried and tested to see if democracy could work in the region and has failed, ipso facto it can be best described as an unfertile ground which resists the spread of democracy and rather upholds authoritarianism. probing the academic literature for a unanimously accepted meaning of democracy, if any, is far from simple or straightforward. It seems, nevertheless, that there is a consensus that democracy principally is ‘a system of governance in which rulers are held accountable for their actions’ (Schmitter and Karl, 1991: 114) and that a society can choose and reinstate those rulers through ‘open, free, and fair’ elections (Huntington, 1991: 9). Democracy is not the ultimate (Touraine, 1997: 28), yet it remains the most valued and proficient forms of government in the world.
conversely, this system of rule still failed to find a grip in the Middle East, a region that has traditionally been a democracy-free zone. This paper seeks to highlight the hurdles that render the Middle East an unfruitful soil for democracy. Therefore, it will be argued that the Middle East lacks many of the democratization prerequisites, such as the adequate political culture and socio-economic grounds. Yet, this could not serve as the main reason why the Middle East is adamant to the spread of democray, as many other countries in Latin America, Africa and Asia succeeded to initiate democratic change even though these prerequisites were absent. The true wonder of the Middle East, this paper argues, lies in ‘The will and capacity of the Arab state’s coercive apparatus to curb democratic initiative’ (Bellin, 2004: 143).
This paper, thus, is structured into three main sections. Firstly, it presents a theoretical overview of authoritarianism in the region, and explores certain salient concepts which are imbedded in this regime; the second section explores the role of the coercive apparatus as a democratization inhibitor will be analysed. In the last section which precedes the conclusion, some democratization obstacles that thwart the consolidation of democracy will be discussed. The conclusion then summarises the argument of the paper.

Authoritarianism in the Middle East – A Theoretical Overview
The question is often asked, why does the Middle East remain largely authoritarian? Or, as it is sometimes posed, why does it continue to experience a democratic deficit (notwithstanding the ongoing developments in the region)? Various scholars have put forward several competing theories and arguments regarding this topic. These tend to fall under four main categories: culture, institutions, the history of international relations and actors in the Middle East, and oil/rentier state.
Scholars such as Samuel Huntington and Ellie Kedourie (1993: 22-49), contend that the lack of democracy in the region stems from the belief that Middle Eastern culture, which they equate with Islam (the reasons for this are discussed in further detail below), is incompatible with democracy.  Huntington (1984: 61) asserts that “Islam has not been hospitable to democracy.” Huntington and other proponents of this view generally argue that Islam’s incompatibility with democracy stems from its system of law, known as Shari’a. Shari’a law lays out the rules and regulations by which Muslims ought to live and links religion and daily life together. Thus, the argument contends, Islamic traditions and values are antithetical to democratic notions of liberty, human rights, and the separation of church and state. According to Elie Kedourie (2000), whereas democracy in the West is based on Western political traditions of constitutions and representational governments, as well as the notion of a sovereign nation state, no equivalent traditions exist within Islam. As a result, Kedourie (2000: 9) asserts, democracy is “quite alien to the mindset of Islam.” Bernard Lewis (2002) discusses the culture argument further. Although he does not specifically address the issue of the persistence of authoritarianism, Lewis (2002) holds essentially the same conclusion.
He argues that the roots of Western dominance (or, more bluntly, Middle Eastern failure to counter it) are found within Islam. Historically speaking, particularly during the last century or so of the Ottoman Empire, Lewis (2002: 21) contends, Islamic beliefs hindered Muslims from fully adopting and assimilating Western cultural norms and values, political practices, and science. Consequently, for a long time the Middle East was slow to “modernize” or “Westernize” and match the progress made by the West; large gaps between the Middle East and the West existed in terms of scientific knowledge, social norms like the status of women, and the separation of religion and the state. When attempts at nationalism and socialism in the 20th century failed to bring about a significant resurgence of Middle Eastern “civilization,” Middle Easterners placed the blame for this elsewhere, particularly towards Western “imperialism.” Instead, Lewis 2002: 23) states that people of the Middle East need to “abandon grievance and victimhood” in order for the region to return its former glory. All of these arguments are rooted in what Edward Said (1979: 6) called “Orientalism.” According to Said (1979: 13), Orientalism is the name for the discourse employed by Europeans and later, Americans, to describe, study, and dominate the Middle East. There is not sufficient space nor is it appropriate for this paper to discuss Orientalism in its entirety. However, one important aspect of it pertains to the culture argument which will be discussed in this paper; it will be based on the notion of the “other.”  The “other” is as an imagined, collective group of people who ought to be feared and considered fundamentally different from another group. In the Orientalist discourse, the West has historically viewed the Orient[1] as the collective “other;” the Orient was a place of exoticism, romance and antiquity, whereas Europe was the place of enlightened, advanced and sophisticated civilization.
In its construction of the notion of the “other,” the discourse regarded the entire Middle East as one unchanging entity, retaining an essential “essence.” Orientalists regarded the religion of Islam as having such an immutable essence and subsequently equated Middle Eastern culture with Islam. When it became clear to scholars that democracy would not spread to the Middle East after the Cold War as it did in other parts of the world, they began to look towards Middle Eastern culture, and hence Islam, as the primary reason for the lack of democracy in the region. Huntington’s (1993: 22) “clash of civilizations” thesis reinforced the notion that culture, rather than nation states, ought to be the main focus of study in the field of international studies.
Other scholars have presented factual data to support the notion of the Islam/democracy divide. Steven Fish (2002) argues through statistical analysis that a strong link exists between Islam and authoritarianism. Specifically, he contends, the subordination of women in Muslim societies is a central factor that accounts for the democratic deficit. According to Fish, variables, such as low female literacy rates, high population sex ratios (a high number of males per 100 females), the lower number of women in government, and weak gender empowerment measures (a variable used by the United Nations Development Program studies to measure the overall status of women in a given society), indicate an overall inferior status of women in Muslim societies. Thus, women’s social standing serves as an important factor that links authoritarianism and Islam.
However, most Middle East political scientists and scholars rejected the idea that culture had anything to do with the persistence of authoritarianism in the region. As Lisa Anderson (2012: 197) states, scholars asserted that Islam was not a monolithic entity; its history demonstrated it to be as tolerant and accommodating like Judaism and Christianity. She points out that followers of Islam and other religions in general have interpreted them in different ways. Furthermore, according to John L. Esposito (2002), all religions, including Islam, have had various relations with different kinds of governments, such as sultanates, democracy, republicanism and monarchy. This evidence indicates that Islam is much like other faiths in that it is capable of existing alongside different kinds of governments at different times. Therefore, it is inaccurate to argue that Islam is incompatible with democracy or any other form of government. The cultural explanation ultimately fails to see the complexity of Middle East, which is as diverse as every other region in the world, and Islam, which is equally varied.
Alternatively, some scholars such as Bellin (2010: 139) have directed their attention to the Middle Eastern institutions instead of culture. Some have argued that the region’s lack of “democratic prerequisites” such as strong civil societies, market driven economies, high literacy rates and representational government institutions accounts for the persistence of authoritarianism in the Middle East. However, the fact that countries in the region possess a number of these so called prerequisites challenges this idea. For example, several countries in the region have democratic institutions such as parliaments, political parties, judiciaries and elections.
According to Marsha P. Posusney (2005: 7), there are two general types of institutions: formal organizations and informal rules and procedures that structure political conduct. These include political parties, government military/security agencies, different branches of government, and elections and the rules that govern them. Stephen Cook (2005) argues that it is not a lack of institutions in the region prevent democratic reform and development, rather, it is the flawed “nature” of the institutions themselves that “tend to restrict political participation, limit individual freedom, and vest overwhelming power in the executive branch of government.”
For example, Cook states that in 2004 citizens of Qatar received greater freedoms in the new constitution, but the royal family consolidated its absolute rule. State manipulation of elections is perhaps the most apparent (and well documented in the literature) means for authoritarian governments in the Middle East to maintain their positions in power. Posusney (2005) illustrates this by describing contested, albeit largely controlled, parliamentary elections throughout Middle East during the early 1960s to 2000. The preferred electoral structure used in the region is a “winner takes all” system, where the party that wins the majority of seats also gains the most power.35 In Egypt, party contested parliamentary elections began under late president Anwar Sadat in 1976. However, according to Posusney, Sadat ensured that the government-backed party would win the majority of the seats, which is what occurred. In 1984, president Hosni Mubarak led a new round of an election but the outcome remained the same: the ruling party, which came to be known as the National Democratic Party, won the majority of the seats, while only garnering 73% of the popular vote.
According to Holger Albrecht and Oliver Schlumberger (2004: 371), in addition to parliaments and elections, authoritarian regimes in the region have also established other institutions such as new government ministries and institutions that arbitrate economic disputes. They have also allowed the establishment of NGOs, parliaments to enact antitrust legislation, and a more open and freer press. The effect of all of these, according to the authors, is the creation of the appearance of democracy for both domestic and foreign audiences. For example, the authors argue, allowing NGOs to operate creates the semblance of autonomous societal organization, and allowing political parties to form creates the appearance of true political contestation. In short, the establishment of institutions is a means and a strategy for authoritarian regimes in the Middle East to claim to have enacted democratic reform when in reality it is more likely the projection of an appearance of democracy. The third set of explanations for the persistence of authoritarianism in the Middle East is the history of international relations with which the region is predominantly about the legacy of foreign, primarily Western, interventionism in to the region during the 20th century and it is directly related to the oil/rentier state theory which this paper will explore.
Middle Eastern oil was (and continues to be) of great geopolitical and economic importance for the entire world. British businessman William Knox D’Arcy first discovered oil in modern day Iran in 1908, but it was not until after World War II that oil would have a significant and long-lasting impact in terms of the potential for democratic prospects in the Middle East.
The oil/rentier state theory is another category of explanations for the persistence of authoritarianism in the Middle East. The theory in this category explores the possible linkages between natural resources and regime type. In other words, scholars within this category examine whether natural resources (such as oil or minerals) determine either democratic or authoritarian political outcomes. Many of these scholars argue the latter. According to Terry Lynn Karl (2008: 7), commodity-led growth causes institutional change within the state; natural resource revenue, more so than any other factors, triggers these kinds of structural alterations. States that undergo such changes are called rentier states.
 According to the theory, rent is income that is not generated by the “productive” processes of a country, that is the wealth generated by a country’s everyday economic activities such as consumption (people’s wages spent on consumer goods), industrial output (manufactured goods to be sold and the profits earned), and taxation. Instead, rent is income derived from “unproductive” sources: the monopoly ownership of land (by the state or foreign companies) and the extraction and selling of natural resources, strategic rents (such as land leased for military bases), foreign worker remittances, foreign aid, and others. Thus the majority of rent comes from external sources.
Karl (2002) defines A rentier-state as a state in which its monopoly ownership of a resource determines the nature of its politics. The rent revenue generated from monopoly ownership determines a state’s political structures. According to the theory, rent income concentrates wealth towards the state, which is the primary recipient and distributor of rent revenues. The state becomes dependent on these revenues and this dependence fundamentally shifts its decision-making process towards maintaining the extraction of rent income in the future. More to the point, the infusion of rents, which are typically very large, allows the state to become relatively autonomous from society. Therefore, the state leaders do not need to (or very minimally so) extract income from society through taxation, and thus be held accountable by society. Their economic independence and the reliance upon official largesse by entire segments of society fosters the concentration of political power in the state.
This, then, gets to the core of the theory’s argument. The theory asserts that states can only “democratize” when the ruler and his subjects bargain over taxes. This happens when the state does not have any source of income to fund its operations other than the taxes it imposes on its subjects. As a result, the state becomes reliant on its citizens and therefore must accommodate their demands, which they express in representative, legislative bodies such as parliaments. In other words, citizens accept taxation in exchange for representation in the state and in this way society is able to hold the government accountable. This relationship is summed up in the phrase “no representation without taxation.”
The state-society relationship is the opposite in rentier states. Society is not involved with the production of national wealth and taxed very little or not at all. Therefore, society has little or no say in state decision-making. However, to offset any opposition or dissent towards the state, rentier states create an apolitical and acquiescent society by providing free or affordable social services in areas such as health care and education. Thus a rentier state bases its authority and legitimacy on the redistribution rent wealth rather than taxation. In sum, according to the theory, rent income is therefore deterministic: it shapes the politics of the state by giving the state the financial autonomy to possess and wield political and economic power. The state becomes powerful, authoritarian, and undemocratic as a result of all of these factors.

Agent of Democratization
The coercive apparatus, including but not limited to the military and security forces, of the authoritarian regime is the most tenacious obstacle in the way of democratization in the Middle East. This apparatus is the instrument whereby the state pursues its monopoly of physical violence within its sovereign territory. This essay suggests that this repressive apparatus has to be at least neutralised first before a democratic transition can start. That is because the security apparatus’ terror and compulsion are the primary tools of subjugating its people (Linz, 2000) and crushing democratic initiatives.
Indeed, it acts as the dictator’s shield. Without the loyalty and support of this stronghold it would be ‘virtually impossible’ for an authoritarian regime to survive (Kassem, 2004: 7). Ensuring this apparatus loyalty ‘entails the constant flow of state patronage’ as well as social and economic incentives (Ibid). Thus, it is not surprising that the Middle Eastern states’ expenditure on security is among the highest in the world (Bellin, 2004: 147). For instance, in 2000, the average spending of Middle Eastern countries on security expenditure was 6.7 percent of their GNP, compared to an international average of 3.8 percent in the same year (Ibid).
In Egypt, for example, since the 1970s, with President Sadat’s political changes in the country, the army’s subordinate role in politics was acceptable in exchange of safeguarding the institution and its leaders’ interests (Harb, 2003). The Egyptian military enjoys increasing economic investing in almost everything. From companies of production of pasta, mineral water, butane gas cylinders, military-gear and gas station services to housing, farming and tourism enterprises (Abul-Magd, 2011; Barany, 2011: 32). ‘The revenue from these enterprises goes straight to the military’s coffers and is disbursed without state oversight’ (Ibid).
Furthermore, it is often difficult to identify the distinction between the despotic regime and the coercive apparatus. As in most cases, the ‘civilian’ ruler, like in Egypt, Algeria or Sudan, is a former military officer. This conflation, along with patrimonial, symbiotic or ethnic linkages between them, makes the coercive apparatus’ elites very hostile towards any gesture of regime change, as they believe that they will be ‘ruined by reform’ (Bermeo, 1997). An unequivocal example is Syria, in which the Alawites, the religious sect of Bashar al-Assad, ‘hold key military positions’ (Pipes, 1989: 429). The army atrociously fights the anti-Assad movement because of the belief that ‘Political opening and popular accountability would deprive the Alawi officer in Syria of his special perquisites, if not his life’ (Bellin, 2004: 149)
During the 2011 Arab uprisings[2], the Arab armies have fiercely quelled the democratic movements in Bahrain, Syria, Libya, and Yemen. Barany (2011: 30) contends that in Tunisia and Egypt, the soldiers ‘backed’ the revolution. However, for various reasons it was only in the Tunisian case that the military did not oppose the democratic change. First, in the heydays of the Egyptian uprising, the military’s top brass did everything in their power to save their supreme commander-in-chief, Hosni Mubarak. They endorsed Mubarak’s plan to transfer some powers to Vice President Omar Suleiman and urged ‘the return of normal life’ (The Huffington Post, 2011), whereas their troops on the ground ‘were actually detaining and abusing protesters’ (Barany, 2011: 31-32). Second, permitting the pro-Mubarak and security elements to attack the peaceful protesters in Tahrir Square, in 2 February, put the military institutional integrity and its domestic legitimacy in jeopardy. Therefore, it was crucial for them to behave as if they were neutral. Third, the army’s abandonment of Mubarak was merely a ‘good strategy to secure the long-term interest of the military elite’ (Franzén, 2012). Finally, on 3 July 2013, because the coercive apparatus remained ‘intact and opposed to political reform’, the military was able to extinguish the hope of political change (Bellin, 2004: 143). Not only has the military ousted Morsi, Egypt’s first democratically elected president, in essence ‘It has ousted democracy’ as well (Gerges, 2013a).
Apart from the coercive apparatus’ role in inhibition of democracy, some Middle East analysts usually forget the complicated evolution of democracy in Europe. It has passed many reformations in the past, and it is unsurprisingly expected to undergo further changes in the future (Maghsoudi and Khorshidi, 2011: 16). Democratization is a complex process, in which no single variable will prove imperative or enough to it (Diamond et al., 1999). Therefore, the subsequent section will review some aspects of the cultural, economic, societal and international factors, which are believed to hinder the consolidation of democracy in the Middle East.

Creed/Faith Playing a Factor
For some historians and political theorists, Islam is perceived to be incompatible with democracy (Huntington: 1991: 298-307; Vatikiotis, 1987). For instance, Bernard Lewis (1958) contends that Islam is inclined to authoritarianism, also Eli Kedourie (1992: 1) views that ‘the idea of democracy is alien to the mind set of Islam’.
Conversely, it is a fallacy, for different reasons, to attribute the lack of democracy in the Middle East to Islam. First, there are other Islamic nations in the  likes of  Indonesia, Turkey and Bangladesh have functioning democratic systems (Chaney in Zakaria, 2012). Second, given the opportunity to play by democratic rules, people in the region enthusiastically participate in the democratic process (BBC, 2011). Third, ‘Catholicism and Confucianism have been accused of incompatibility with democracy, yet these cultural endowments have not prevented countries in Latin America, southern Europe, and East Asia from democratizing.’ (Bellin, 2004: 141).
On the other hand, some analysts contend that it is an ‘Arab’ rather than ‘Muslim’ democracy gap (Stepan and Robertson, 2003). Albeit, the 2011 Arab uprisings and the fact that ‘for decades’ people in the region have been resisting and protesting against unrepresentative and oppressive regimes’ Franzén (2012), disprove this claim.
Yet, all religions, including Islam, ‘require some level of hermeneutics to give them meaning in specific contexts’ (Bromley, 1997: 333). Thus, the problem is that ‘some interpretations such as those favoured by radical Islamists conflict with democratic ideals’ (Otterman, 2003). Some of them are hostile to democracy because they believe that only God’s laws, al-Shari’a, must be implemented (Ibid). Another problem, given the weight of Islamist opposition movements in the Arab world, is the fear that ‘Islamists would only participate in elections to win power and put an end to democracy immediately’ (Ottaway and Carothers, 2004). Some could argue that, this is what Egypt’s deposed president, Morsi, has done shortly after his first few months in office, when he granted himself sweeping powers and ‘immunity from legal oversight’ (Beaumont, 2012). On the other hand, as considerable portions of the region’s peoples support the Islamist movements, it seems that without their inclusion, democracy is impossible in the Middle East (Ottaway and Carothers, 2004).
Nevertheless, with respect to Islam, and in order to help democracy settle in the Middle East, there are some efforts need to be done. For instance, the Islamic scholars should resume the endeavours of ‘Islamic modernism and revivalism’ that were nurtured by ideas of prominent religious leaders like that of the Islamic jurist Mohammed ‘Abdu (Dawn, 1991: 8). They should scrutinize the Islamic heritage, history and literature in order to provide the people with clear answers to questions about the relation between Islam and democracy.
In addition, for the Islamist parties, they need to revamp their views, and offer real guarantees to the public and non-Islamists parties to emphasize their adherence to the rules of the democratic game. Conversely, it is still early to gauge the Islamists’ experiment in post-revolutionary Tunisia, it could be useful to contrast their success in supporting the democratic transition and cooperating with other factions in Tunisia, the trajectory of the Muslim Brothers in post-Mubarak Egypt.

Cultural, Societal and Historical Factors
Democracy, to Ayubi (2001: 397), is not merely a system of governance, ‘it is also a cultural and intellectual tradition’. By culture, sociology defines it as the way a group of people live; this may include the food they eat, the clothe they wear, where they profess their creed (religion) and so on. Consequently, it could be argued that, in the Middle East, the high levels of illiteracy and widespread autocratic, patriarchal and masculine traditions in both family and society impose a serious problem to acknowledging the democratic values (Crystal, 2001).
Not only the poor illiterate portions of the community that make the boulevard of democratization bumpy, but also the disc of the business, religious, academic, public servants and military elites who choose to ally with the authoritarian government, in exchange for incentives, benefits and the state’s patronage. In the region, ‘Missing until now are elites committed to serious rather than cosmetic reform’ in the economic and social structures in their states (Norton, 2009: 146).
Norton (2009: 130) opines that ‘the region’s governments are not simply undemocratic but anti-democratic’ which implies that they are resistant to the spread of democracy. This disdain for democracy date back to the founding of the Arab republics, in the 1950s and 1960s, when openly military dictatorships replaced the partial democracies of the colonial period in Egypt, Iraq and Syria (Bromley, 1997: 327). In that era, democracy was portrayed as ‘nationally divisive’ and a Western tool (Ibid). President Nasser viewed the partial parliamentary democracy in Egypt, during the period 1923 to 1952, as nothing more than ‘an easy tool for the reimbursements of the feudal system’ (BBC in Owen, 2004: 133).
In consistency with the anti-democracy legacy of the Arab systems, there was no ‘fairly strong institutional separation of the realm of politics from the overall system in society’ (Rueschemeyer et al., 1992: 41-58). Moreover, absent were the checks and balances within the state system, which is overwhelmingly controlled by the authoritarian leader. Furthermore, the civil society that could have played an intermediary’ role between the individual and the state, as well as ‘a constitutive role by redefining the political game along democratic lines’ (White, 2004: 14-15), has been undermined and fizzled out as a result of the regimes’ containment and repressive policies (Kassem, 2004: 126-7).

Socio-economic and Development Factors
If we follow the international financial institutions’ doctrine that the path to democracy starts from liberalised economy (Norton, 2009: 137), it might be argued that the Middle Eastern countries have a democracy problem, in part, because of the lack of the adequate economic preconditions. Generally, there are some common socio-economic features in the region. For instance, the public sector remains the major employer in the state. In addition, in most cases, the state is rentier, which means that the state depends mainly on the rents rather than taxation. According to Beblawi (1987: 383), the rent is generally ‘a reward for ownership of all natural sources’, like the oil wealth in Gulf countries. To put it another way, it is ‘the income derived from the gift of the nature’ (Marshall, 1920).
While Huntington (1991: 65) argues that ‘broad-based economic development involving significant industrialization may contribute to democratization’, he suggests that oil-based economies do not. In Huntington’s opinion, the oil revenues accrue to the state, and this helps to fortify the state bureaucracy and, lessen the need for taxation. Consequently, the absence of taxation disengages the citizens and separates the state from the society. Just as if the state pays in exchange for silence and obedience of its citizens. Luciani (1994: 132) asserts that ‘The roots of democratic institutions are in the state’s need to tax in order to support its activities’.
In 2011, in the awake of the Arab uprisings, the Saudi King’s plan to save his throne was spending ‘an unprecedented amount of money, more than £60bn ($100bn) and counting’ on raising salaries, helping people to buy houses, and benefits for the unemployed citizens (Buchanan, 2011). Therefore, in a sense, oil could be a curse, when it becomes ‘a factor perpetuating authoritarian government’ (Luciani, 1994: 131). In keeping with this view, Ross (2011) suggests that citizens of the Arab countries with little or no oil generally had more freedom than those of lots of it.
Similarly, foreign aid is one of the sources of the rents. For instance, the United States provides Egypt with $1.55 billion as annual aid package. This aid, in part, does help the government reduce its dependence on the conventional taxation (Norton, 2009: 136). Egypt, the second largest recipient of US aid (Sharp, 2010), and some other Middle East countries are among the most dependent and vulnerable countries in the world (Ayubi, 2001: 401). This vulnerability and dependence is closely linked to the discussion of international obstacles in the following part.

International Interference
The international patronage, occasionally, plays a key role in sustaining and stabilizing the authoritarian regime and its coercive apparatus. This notion was proven in Latin America and Europe by the end of the Cold War, as the withdrawal of American patronage of the Latin American dictatorships and the cease of Brezhnev doctrine to support Eastern European communist systems quicken the pace of the fall of these regimes (Janos, 2000). Contrarily, in the Middle East, the patronage continued as the authoritarian regimes secured the Western interests in the region, which revolve around the security of Israel, the access to oil, and containing the Islamist threat (Bellin, 2004).
Despite the American rhetoric of supporting democracy and human rights in the region, the truth is that the USA has long been and remains a key ally of tyrannical Arab regimes. In the time was President Clinton, in the 1990s, talking about promoting democracy all over the world, his prominent aid, Martin Indyk (2002), viewed democracy in the Middle East as a chaos-inducer, and detrimental to Israel. Indyk’s perspective reflects the long-standing tradition of the US foreign policy in the region; upholding the status quo, as working with the dictators is better than dealing with what might democracy produce. The fact that ‘American policy in the Middle East has never been historically pro-democratic’ (Ayubi, 2001: 402) was emphasized in the words of Madeleine Albright (2003), the former Secretary of State; ‘we did not make democracy a priority. Arab public opinion, after all, can be rather scary’.
Even in the aftermath of the 9/11 attacks, when the Bush administration decided to break the conventional American foreign policy and adopt a unilateral, interventionist agenda in the Middle East where the US enjoyed an intimate relationship with despots, promoting democracy was merely rhetorical. In July 2003, with the Anglo-American invasion of Iraq, the British Prime Minister Tony Blair stated before the US Congress, ‘We promised Iraq democratic government. We will deliver it’ (CNN, 2003). In August 2003, Condoleezza Rice declared ‘a generational commitment to helping the people of the Middle East transform their region’ into a democratic zone (Milbank, 2004). Furthermore, in November 2003, President Bush reiterated the commitment of the USA to the goal of promoting liberal democracy and market-driven economy throughout the entire Middle East (Bush, 2003).
On the contrary, there was a mismatch between this pro-democracy discourse and actions in reality. The Bush administration turned a blind eye to human rights violations and authoritarianism in Saudi Arabia, Egypt, Jordan and elsewhere in the Muslim world (Abootalebi, 2007: 427). Freedman suggests that ‘emancipation was not the reason why the Bush administration went to Iraq war. For Rumsfeld and Cheney, the war was about solving the Saddam problem rather than the Iraq problem, about bringing security rather than justice’ (2006: 134).
Distancing itself from Bush’s interventionist and tarnished legacy, the Obama administration returned to the traditional realist line of Middle Eastern policy. During the Arab uprisings, Obama stayed reluctant to side with the democratic uprising of Egypt until it became obvious that Mubarak could not continue (Gerges, 2013b). Also, his administration was ‘reticent to support the Bahraini uprising because the Bahraini monarchy best serves U.S. regional interests’ (Hughes, 2011). Likewise, during the Tunisian uprising, France supported Ben Ali ‘right up to the moment he fled’ (Chrisafis, 2011).
Not only was America pro-tyrants, but occasionally it moved against democratically elected regimes. For instance, in Iran, in 1953, the CIA was involved in a clandestine operation, codenamed Operation Ajax, to overthrow the elected prime minister of Iran and return the pro-America shah to his throne (Bill, 1988: 86-94). Also, when the Islamic Resistance Movement Hamas won the Palestinian elections in 2006, the ‘US plotted to overthrow Hamas’ government (Goldenberg, 2008).
A fair assessment of the Western role in Middle East might bring us back to Thomas Jefferson’s observation on the world of his days: ‘We believe no more in Bonaparte’s fighting merely for the liberties of the seas than in Great Britain’s fighting for the liberties of mankind. The object is the same, to draw to themselves the power, the wealth and the resources of other nations’ (Chomsky, 2003).

Concluding Remarks
Explaining the paradigm of democratisation in the Middle East is ‘a complex business’ (Bromley, 1997: 340). Throughout this essay, the main accounts for the region’s democracy deficit have been classified into three main categories. Firstly, the theoretical overview of authoritarianism which has densely influenced the entire system in the region. Secondly, the Arab state’s coercive apparatus which acts as a democratisation agent. The existence of this apparatus intact and opposed to political change means that a democratic transition cannot be initiated at all, and herein lies the singularity, if any, of the Middle East. Thirdly, this paper has refuted some fallacies and erroneous conclusions  regarding the incompatibility of Islamic or Arabic culture with democracy. In addition, it was argued that democratisation obstacles such as an inadequate literacy rate and socio-economic arrangements, the weakness of civil society and the Western support for the region’s dictatorships rendered the region an infertile soil for democracy. Finally, despite the Arab Spring’ disappointing consequence, and the democratisation problems in the region, there is still hope. This hope is incarnated in the revolutionary Tunisian march for a better hope, in which Tunisia is stepping forward ‘on its path to democracy, shattering stereotypes and setting an example for others to follow.’ (Abdessalem, 2014).





Bibliography
Acharya, Viral and Matthew Richardson. 2009. ‘Causes of the Financial Crisis’.
Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society 21(2): 195-210.
Bakir, Caner. 2013. Bank Behaviour and Resilience: The Effect of Structures, Institutions and Agents.
 London: Palgrave Macmillan.
Beck, Thorsten, Diane Coyle, Mathias Dewatripont, Xavier Freixas and Paul Seabright. 2010. ‘Bailing out the Banks: Reconciling Stability and Competition’. Centre for Economic Policy Research (CEPR).
Available at:  http://dev3.cepr.org/pubs/other/Bailing_out_the_banks.pdf. [Accessed] 15 April 2018.
Bell, Stephen and Hui Feng. 2013. The rise of the People’s Bank of China: the politics of institutional change.
 Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Bell, Stephen and Andrew Hindmoor. 2015a. Masters of the Universe, Slaves of the Market.
Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Bell, Stephen and Andrew Hindmoor. 2015b. ‘Masters of the Universe but Slaves of the Market: Bankers and the Great Financial Meltdown’.
British Journal of Politics and International Relations 17(1): 1-22.
Bourdieu, Pierre. 1977. Outline of a Theory of Practice. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Ciro, Tony. 2012. The Global Financial Crisis: Triggers, Responses and Aftermath.
Surrey: Ashgate Publishing Limited.
Crotty, James. 2002. ‘Trading state-led prosperity for market-led stagnation: from the Golden Age to global neoliberalism’.
In Seeking Shelter on the Pacific Rim: Financial Globalisation, Social Change and the Housing Market, eds. G. Dymski and D. Isenberg. New York: M. E. Sharpe Inc.
Crotty, James. 2009. ‘Structural causes of the global financial crisis: a critical assessment of the ‘new financial architecture’.
Cambridge Journal of Economics 33(4): 563-580.
Diamond, Douglas and Raghuram Rajan. 2001. ‘Liquidity risk, liquidity creation and financial fragility: a theory of banking’.
 Journal of Political Economy 109(2): 287-327.
Ellis, Luci. 2009. ‘The Global Financial Crisis: Causes, Consequences and Countermeasures’. Reserve Bank of Australia (RBA)
Available at:
 [Assessed 4April, 2018]
Financial Services Authority (FSA). 2009. ‘The Turner Review:
A Regulatory Response to the Global Banking Crisis’. London: FSA.
Garnaut, Ross. 2009. The Great Crash of 2008. Melbourne:
Melbourne University Press.
Giddens, Anthony. 1979. Central Problems in Social Theory:
Action, Structure and Contradiction in Social Analysis. Los Angeles: University of California Press.
Gowan, Peter. 2009. ‘Crisis in the Heartland:
Consequences of the New Wall Street System’. New Left Review 55: 5-29.
Helleiner, Eric. 2011. ‘Understanding the 2007-2008 Global Financial Crisis:
Lessons for Scholars of International Political Economy’. Annual Review of Political Science 14: 67-87.
Keaney, Michael. 2012. ‘Tackling the Financial Crisis’.
Political Studies Review 10(1): 63-72.
Mishkin, Frederic. 1999a. ‘Global financial instability: framework, events, issues’.
Journal of Economic Perspectives 13(4): 3-20.
Mishkin, Frederic. 1999b. ‘Lessons from the Asian crisis’.
Journal of International Money and Finance 18(4): 709-723.
Peláez, Carlos M. and Carlos A. Peláez. 2009. Regulation of Banks and Finance.
London: Palgrave Macmillan.
Porter, Tony. 2005. Globalisation and Finance. Cambridge: Polity.
Sewell, William. 1992. ‘A Theory of Structure:
Duality, Agency and Transformation’. American Journal of Sociology 98(1): 1-29.
Swamy, Vigneshwara. 2012. ‘Financial instability, uncertainty and bank lending behaviour’.
 International Journal of Banking and Finance 9(4): 74-95.
Wallenstein, Stephen. 2009. ‘The roots of the financial crisis’.
 Capital Markets Law Journal 4(3): 8-30.
White, Ben. 2009. ‘What Red Ink? Wall Street Paid Hefty Bonuses’.
The New York Times.
Available at: http://www.nytimes.com/2009/01/29/business/29bonus.html?_r=0 [Assessed April 19, 2018]
Wolf, Martin. 2009. ‘Seeds of its own destruction’.
 Financial Times.




[1] The ‘Orient’ referred to not only the Middle East but also the entire Asian continent and North Africa.
[2] The Arab Spring or Uprising was a series of anti-government protests, uprisings and armed rebellions that spread across the Middle East in early 2011.

Why the Middle East Remains a Region Wrecked by Violence and other forms of Upheavals


Introduction
Among the many captivating issues which capture the banner headlines of various news prints is the persistent unrest and conflicts within the Middle East Region. As such, in broaching the issue of conflicts and the various forms of upheavals in the Region, the region’s complex nature cannot be overemphasised. Factors constituting to the upheavals ranges from territorial disputes to religious extremism or fundamentalism; from the politics of water to conflicts over rich minerals such as oil; from authoritarian regime to issues over gender and human rights and inter alia. Over the years, the Region has seen various forms of conflicts emanating from the factors listed above, ipso facto, it is worthy to note that the conflicts do not only depend on these alone. There are other factors which may include  first, the imperial carving up of the region to suit the interests of the European colonial powers, which cut across all kinds of ethnic, religious and tribal lines, creating new artificial, legal borders, and even entirely new states.
This had a destabilizing effect on the region, as these new borders were usually not regarded as legitimate (Fawcett, 2005). Second, is the creation of the Zionist State of Israel, with the dual outcome of the loss of the Palestinian homeland, and the massive displacement of refugees across the region. Third, and in more recent times, the invasions of Iraq  and the deployment of US troops in the Gulf states and Saudi Arabia totally altered the balance of power in the region and inflamed the hearts of many contemporary jihadist’s including Osama bin Laden (Atwan 2006). A fourth, factor would be the region’s oil wealth and thus, strategic and economic importance to a hegemonic power, trying to attain a critical leverage over any challenging power.  Although, these factors are of the upmost importance, it is beyond the scope of this essay to analyse them any further. The argument here is that, there are several other factors which forms the basis of the upheavals in the region, but for the purpose of this paper, only three of these factors will be explored.  In this regard, this paper will examine the disparity around the politics of water in the region, the discrepancies around oil as a sustaining factor to authoritarian regime which hinders democracy and the hindrance of democracy gives birth to various forms of agitations which sometimes amounts to series of protest such as the Arab Spring, and lastly religious extremism which is more of a hermeneutical concept.  
The Paper argues that these key issues have been a gargantuan contributing factor to upheavals  in the region. As such, the paper is divided into three sections (which exclude the introduction and conclusion); the first part reviews water politics as a major source of upheavals in the region; the second part takes a look at religious extremism which the paper argues that, such approach to religion breeds terrorism which in turn creates conflicts and other forms of upheavals. The paper further substantiates its argument that, when religion is viewed through a myopic lens, it nurtures religious fundamentalism/extremism. The third section explores the discrepancies over the oil well and worth as a sustaining factor which hinders the seed of democracy from being sown, and this in turn breeds agitations which fuels protests; and the conclusion summarises the various arguments of the paper.

General Overview of water Scarcity in the Region and Water Sovereignty
Among the many issues which constitutes to the entire hullabaloo about water in the region, it is worthy to note that the region has been adversely affected by climate change. This has led to the entire Middle East becoming dryer, thus meaning that water volumes, be it in aquifers or river basins, are declining.  According to Norton (2005) the aquifers are not being recharged at optimal levels due to a decrease in annual rainfall and because of over-pumping by humans, which has upset the delicate equilibrium of the hydrological cycle. The extent to which this can be reversed is unknown. The region is also experiencing more frequent and longer lasting droughts. The severe water strain is causing the desertification of arable land used for agriculture, which in turn destroys the livelihood of the majority of people in the region.
Therefore, water scarcity is steadily affecting food supply. This is a crisis when we combine the issue of a rising population in the region. A larger population will need more water and food resources, which are already at break point. Also, the rising living standards across the region will mean that per capita, there will be more consumer demand for water to be used in daily life. When all three factors are added together the situation looks bleak (Farrant, 2007).
Water is a contentious issue for states because it does not neatly fit into the legal parameters of a state. The psycho-political borders of a state cannot usually extend to completely encompass a water system. Hence, water is a trans-boundary resource, unlike, say a diamond mine. Water’s natural tendency to flow over and under vast sways of land, cutting across state borders, makes it highly difficult and expensive to control and measure. Also, water maybe conceptualized as a zero-sum game, in that, when one party utilizes some, it directly affects the amount left for the other parties. The legal questions over who has rights over water have no consensus as yet. Such questions are, for example, who owns a river that flows within two states. Is it the upstream state where the river begins, or the downstream state where the water ends? Such a fundamental question over water sovereignty is nevertheless very complex once the involved parties have to decide exactly how to split the volume of water they are each entitled to (Jobson, 2003).

From the Euphrates to the Nile and the West Bank: the potential for violence
Flint and Waal (2008) opine that water can be a divisive issue within the region. In order to illustrate this, I shall now consider the politics surrounding the region’s most important river basins: firstly, the Tigris and Euphrates. Modern day Turkey has the advantaged position of being the upstream party. This means that Turkey has the power to be able to affect the flow of the rivers into the downstream states, which include such countries as Syria and Iraq, among others. Both these states are highly dependent on the continuous flow of these rivers to irrigate their scarce arable land. Moreover, Turkey has invested heavily into water infra-structure. Its project for utilizing its water is called the Anatolian Project. This includes 66 dams, 60 hydro-electric stations and many drainage and irrigation schemes. Such a vast project significantly hinders the amount of water flowing into the downstream parties thus negatively affecting them both, socially and economically.
Since the 1970’s, Syria and Iraq had been working together to put political pressure on Turkey to adopt a water sharing arrangement, which would take their needs into account. However, the invasion of Iraq in 2003 has taken Iraq out of the water equation, and consequently made Turkey stronger. Iraq has been left out of water sharing agreements by the other parties (Orr, 2009). This has had a devastating effect on Iraq. It has seen 36% of its total arable land turn to desert in an irreversible way, which has led to 3.3 million Iraqi’s displaced and forced to live on the outskirts of the cities in Latin America-style, shanty towns. Such a situation is very unstable and will cause a lot of resentment within Iraq and may perpetuate the internal conflict for longer (Jobson, 2003).
The second river basin I will reflect on will be the Nile basin. The power make-up in the Nile basin is almost a reversal of the Tigris-Euphrates situation. Egypt is a downstream state. However, it has power relative to the upstream states. This is only due to the extensive investment in water infra-structure that Egypt has carried out, first during colonial rule under Britain, and then pursued independently thereafter (Allan, 1999). Water security is of vital importance to Egypt because only 5% of its land is viable for agriculture and hospitable to live on, thus making water control a matter of high politics. The upstream parties are east African states with a much more lush landscape relative to most of the Middle East. These states were actually hindered in their development of water works by the British in order to secure Egypt’s control. Since independence, they lack the expertise, technology and capital to develop such complex and expensive infrastructure (Flint and Waal, 2008).  However, once these states do utilize their water resources and begin to hinder the flow to Egypt, the situation may become very volatile. Egypt has already stated that under the current regime, Egypt would only go to war for water.
 Without an adequate and enforceable water sharing arrangement, conflict could be inevitable. Already Sudan is experiencing severe water shortages although to what level it is caused by Egypt or climate change is unknown. Sudan’s arable land is also very scarce. Therefore, the loss of huge sways of grazing land is a catastrophe. Lakes and wells which have allowed cattle and camel herders to live in peace for hundreds of years have all but dried up, leaving the herders to fight over what is left or lose not just their livelihoods but their entire way of life. The Bedouin camel herders can no longer follow the well known desert routes because the wells they depend on are dry. Thus a conflict for land and water resources has exacerbated the other conflicts in Sudan pushing rival communities to violence (Flint, 2008).
In respect to the Jordan basin, one must remember that the volumes are much less relative to the Nile or the Tigris-Euphrates. Israel, the water hegemon of the Levant, due to its water infra-structure and high-tech industry is currently experiencing a continual and deepening water crisis. This is a security threat to the sustainability of the State in itself. Thus, it reduces the possibilities for political negotiations with other parties.  With this, Anthon (2007) cites an example with the West Bank. The West Bank is relatively rich in water, due to ground water within its three major aquifer systems. These aquifers are the reason why the Israel’s internationally condemned settlements continue to expand. A look at the geography would indicate that they are directly positioned to correlate with the high ground on top of the aquifers. Thus the settlements have abundance of water and arable land. Also, from their high latitude on top of the hills they can control the flow of water downward, thus making the Palestinians totally dependent on them for water (Anon, 2009).
The Palestinians have not been allowed to develop their own water infrastructure and the walled settlements are actually separating them from their water and land resources. This shows that a Palestinian State in the West Bank is not a possible option for Israel. Already experiencing a water crisis and unsure future, it cannot give up the rich West Bank, which it feels is vital for its water security. Therefore, the only possible option of a Palestinian State in the West Bank will be a semi-autonomous cluster of unviable cantons with total water dependence on Israel. The Golan Heights also present a political obstacle to negotiations and friendly relations with Israel’s neighbouring states. Israel is holding on to the Heights because they are strategically important to protect the Sea of Galilee, which is the main water supply of Israel. Therefore, until water issues can be resolved they are a major source of instability and an obstacle to peace in the region (Allan, 1999).
Tenably, Water, although a divisive issue, can also have the potential to foster greater cooperation. It is hopeful that there has not of yet been a water war in recorded history. The closest a war solely fought for water has ever come to materializing was in 1975 when Syria sent her troops to the Syrian-Turkish border in retaliation for Turkey’s unilateral decision to fill the Ataturk Dam, significantly harming Syria’s economy temporarily (Jobson, 2003). Whereas wars have been fought with water as a factor, it is usually sidelined and as only of secondary importance to the conventional war aims of a state.

Religious Extremism/Fundamentalism being a factor of the upheavals
The Middle East is one of the most religiously diverse regions in the world.  Besides being home to holy sites for the three main Abrahamic religions  Christianity, Islam and Judaism, this region houses religions including Zoroastrianism, the Druze religion, Buddhism, Yaziti, Samaritanism and the Baha’i faith, among many others.  According to a World Values Survey report that collected data between 2005-2007, 93 percent of residents of nine Middle Eastern countries Egypt, Turkey, Saudi Arabia, Morocco, Jordan, Israel, Iraq, Iran and Algeria  said that God was “very important” in their lives.  Meanwhile, only about 53 percent of United States citizens responded alike on the same survey.  This medley of beliefs can lead to difference in opinion and conflict, which often leads to religious disputes in the region.

Religious forces
There are many fundamentalist religious forces acting in Egypt, Saudi Arabia, Iran, Iraq, and other Middle East countries. Even though fundamentalists do not automatically equate to extremists or terrorists, there are many Middle East adherents to the religious writings of Taqi al Din ibn Taymiyyah (1269-1328), Sayyid Qutb (1906-1966) (White, 2006), and Muhammad ibn Abdul Wahhab (1703-1787) (Marsden,2002) that preach not only Islamic conservatism but violent rejection of other religions and violence against nonbelievers. This adds to the fact that the region is not only an Islamic territory but also has the core foundation of some other religions such as Christianity and Judaism. Some of the early modern fundamentalist precepts were voiced by the Muslim Brotherhood, founded in Egypt in 1928 by Hassan al-Banna. At that time, the Brotherhood’s leadership saw great social injustice and economic disparity in Egypt (White, 2006). In seeking to establish that Islam was a religion encompassing all aspects of political, social, and economic life, it was the Brotherhood that first proposed a government based on Islamic religious principles. In addition, some Brotherhood members advocated the right of a movement to take up arms against ‘impure’ Muslims and regarded Shari’a as governing civil as well as religious life. Building upon the Brotherhoods’ teachings, Qutb’s writings justified jihad to oppose those in power (Marsden, 2002a).
These teachings provided extremists religious justification for opposing Muslim secular regimes as well as conservative, but autocratic, Islamic governments. In a tragic example for his role in signing a peace agreement with Israel, Egyptian president Anwar Sadat was assassinated in 1981 by members of Egyptian Islamic Jihad, a radical terrorist group with roots in the Muslim Brotherhood.

As much as the preceding Muslim fundamentalist philosophers influenced individuals like Osama Bin Laden and his mentor, Abdullah Azzam, there was perhaps no greater fundamentalist upheaval than the 1979 Iranian Islamic revolution. Previously there had been political revolutions founded in Islam resulting in the overthrow of colonial powers; Algeria for example. However, Ayatollah Ruhollah Khomeini organized a popular revolt based on a return to fundamentalism and the rule of Shari’a law. Following the successful overthrow of the Shah of Iran, Khomeini launched his own vision of an Islamic caliphate using violence in the form of support for Hizballah (Marsden, 2002b). It may be said that modern Middle East religious terrorism began as a function of the Iranian revolution. In fact, in 1968 there were no identifiable religious terrorist groups. That number had increased to 2 in 1980, 11 in 1992 and 26 in 1995, nearly half of the total number of terrorist organizations for that year identified by Bruce Hoffman (1999) in the Rand Review.

Interestingly, in 1995 terrorist acts committed in the name of religion accounted for only 25 percent of the terrorist incidents, but accounted for 58 percent of the fatalities (Hoffman, 1998). The influence of religion cannot be underestimated when discussing forces contributing to Islamic extremism in the region. Bin Laden and his followers see the current struggle with the West as a long, defensive, historical struggle blessed by Allah (Abdella, 2003). Suicide bombers go to their targets with thoughts of martyrdom and heavenly rewards. Some radical clerics also provide the spiritual guidance and approval allegedly required prior to a mass killing or other type of terrorist attack. Finally, the influence of Muslim clerics can currently be seen in Iraq as Muqtada al-Sadr has demonstrated with his potential to incite the Shi’a masses. Conversely, other clerics such as Grand Ayatullah Sayyid Ali Husayni Sistani hold impeccable religious credentials that could influence populations in a positive manner should they choose to do so. In so far as the region is endowed with such a tremendous religious traditions, the fundamental approach to the issue of faith pose a threat to the peace and tranquillity of the region, and with such attitude to religion, conflicts and upheavals persists and prevails.

Why would oil hinder democracy and Uphold authoritarian regime?

This section will present three causal mechanisms that might explain the alleged link between oil exports and authoritarian rule: a rentier effect, a repression effect, and a modernization effect. These serve as compendium of causes in the sustenance of authoritarian regimes which has over the years, and its effects constituted to the unrest and upheavals in the region.

The Rentier Effect
 The so called “rentier states “derive a large share of their revenues from external rent, i.e. oil, minerals, foreign aid. In certain countries with large oil exports, the state is thus largely financed directly by oil rents (Luciani, 2013: 114). The general argument is that these states use their oil revenues to counter mounting social pressures that could potentially lead to claims for more accountable government. The first component of the argument is that rentier states are independent of society, as they are not forced collect taxes. This in turn implies that people are less likely to demand representation and accountability from their government.
The second component is that oil wealth allows for spending on patronage or paternalism, which helps forestall any latent pressures for democratization. In other words, large and unrestrained budgets make “fiscal pacification” effective (Norton, 2013: 134). A third component involves a well-financed and oversized state apparatus that might help prevent the formation of social groups independently of the state. The lack of group formation inhibits the development of an independent bourgeoisie as well as the emergence of civil society and social capital both said to be important requisites of democracy (Ross, 2001: 334).

Repression effect
 In another perspective, the flow of hydrocarbon rents finances repression, which in turn diminishes the capacity of populations to mount challenges to autocratic regimes. An extensive security apparatus as well as military is in the interest of the wealthy authoritarian government, who wants to defend itself against popular pressures (Ross, 2001: 335).

Modernization effect
 According to modernization theory, democracy is a product of a collection of social and cultural changes (example education, urbanization, specialization) that are caused by economic development. However, the link is not due to wealth per se, and resource-led growth will not necessarily entail the relevant societal changes resulting in a gradual democratization from below.

In sum, the rentier effect entails governments using high spending and low tax rates to ease democratic pressure; the repression effect means that governments employ a well-fed security apparatus to fend off pressures (any form of pressure which might cause agitation as a result of the system/regime); and finally the modernization effect implies a superficial economic development not bringing about the social forces that might otherwise foster pushes for political liberalization

 Caveat to the Oil Explanation
However tempting it might be, one should be wary when concluding that oil is the sole factor explaining the democratic deficit. Importantly, one should have in mind that the argument logically does not apply to the largely non-oil autocracies of Jordan, Morocco, Syria, Egypt and Yemen. In the same vein, Ross (2001) estimates that, on overage, countries in the Middle East are about 30 % less democratic than countries outside the region, even  after accounting for the effects of economic development and oil.  In other words, to get a more nuanced understanding oil’s effects on the regimes of the region (i.e. not to overestimate it), one should also understand other factors ‘working against’ democracy.
Larry Diamond (2010), for instance, argues that geopolitics has played an important role beyond the important factor of oil. Strategic interest by the Soviet Union, but now mainly Europe and the United States have prompted external support for Arab autocratic that has conferred crucial economic resources and security assistance. In the case of non-oil regimes such as Egypt, Jordan, and Morocco, of foreign aid has had virtually the same effect as oil: it has flowed into the central coffers of the state and allowed cooption and repression.
A case in point is Egypt receiving vast amounts of US assistance since 1975 (ibid: 101). Moreover, The Arab-Israeli conflict has served as a convenient means of diverting public discontent away from the lack of quality education, social services, jobs, accountability and freedom. Furthermore, the Arab states reinforce each other in their authoritarianism and repression. A recent example for this would be the Saudi-supported suppression of the revolts in Bahrain. Beyond all this, the lack of especially Arab democracies (perhaps except for Lebanon for a short period) imply that there is no source of potentially important democratic diffusion inside the Arab world.
Another factor inhibiting the democratic prospects of the region is the fear that hard-line Islamist might come to power through the democratic process. This prospect potentially diminishes domestic support for democracy among otherwise typically democratic forces (middle-class liberal intellectuals, professionals, and businessmen) and may also imply less Western pressure and advocacy for democracy in the region.
Finally, Hariri (2012, 2015) presents a structural explanation of the democratic deficit in the region focusing on the deep roots of democratization and colonial history. The diffusion of institutions through European colonial settlement has been an important factor in spreading the early seeds of democracy. Hariri (2012) argues that the Middle East had relatively well-developed pre-colonial state institutions and was therefore long able to resist European colonization and settlement. When territories were colonized, they were more likely to experience an indirect form of colonial rule. As such, traditional authority structures have persisted and, in the long run, these territories were less likely to become democracies. One of the key feature of the repressive nature of the regimes in the region is the effects of the Arab Spring; it can be argued that the region’s authoritarian nature triggered the uprising where the populace felt the pinch of the repression even to the extent of not being able to freely express themselves.

Concluding Remarks

For the stability of the greater region, I feel that it is imperative for the Arab-Israeli conflict to be resolved. However, as I mentioned above, water is a significant barrier to developing a just peace without structural violence, which would cripple negotiations from the start and destine them to unravel. Therefore, cooperation between Israel and its neighbours over water could be a source for dampening insecurity.
Summing up the arguments around religious extremism, the arguments herein fall into two consistent themes (1) that certain forces exist in the Middle East that cause and perpetuate Middle East extremism and (2) that the Arab world is caught in a time warp between its unique cultures and traditions and the influences of the modern world. Essentially, then, the Middle East is divided into at least two competing philosophies. One is struggling the need to co-exist, which most times causes upheavals and frictions, and prosper within the context of 21st century politics and economics, and the other completely rejects contemporary political or socioeconomic advances in the world community, maintaining a strict adherence to Shari’a law (which is really a fundamental approach to the Islamic code). One philosophy tends to be at least willing to explore the concept of democratic and global market economic principles and the other seeks to maintain a large proportion of the world’s population in a state of constant turmoil and turbulence in order to establish their own ideals based on religious zealotry.
The obvious question that comes to mind when considering these two competing philosophies is what is ‘best’ for the Middle East populace? From a Western perspective, and likely most countries with stable governments, the choice is obvious. The philosophy of co-existence equates to stable Middle East as a region rid of chaos and upheavals. That is not to say that improvements cannot be made within the current Middle East political system. Western governments should continually push for greater political representation and more market oriented economies in the Middle East. However, if the philosophy of co-existence is to be made attractive to the majority of the Middle East populace, then the problem becomes one of how to address the forces earlier identified as contributing to continued Islamic extremism and terrorist activities in a manner that mitigates or eliminates these forces. The answers to this problem are complicated but should be given focus among current Middle East leaders because they, in the long term, are the individuals that are going to have to try to institute a populist message that will engage the Islamic street; the assumption being that individuals will reject extremism and terrorism when guaranteed political representation and greater economic opportunity.
How that can be accomplished is left to individual leaders because the Middle East is a vast mixture of cultures, and only those individuals that ostensibly know their peoples and have the political fortitude and desire to extend a populist message will succeed.
Western governments can offer subtle, background encouragement and guidance, but the message needs to originate from within the Middle East. Unfortunately, it is probable that if those forces fuelling extremism are not addressed to the satisfaction of the majority of Middle Eastern populations, then Islamic extremism and resultant terrorist activities will continue unabated.
This essay has argued that oil has indeed been a curse for democracy in the region, where authoritarianism is still strongly entrenched. With oil appearing a very important impediment to democracy, a prolonged, decline in oil prices and future energy technology, rendering the world less dependent on oil, could very well be the indirect forces that make the region embark on a democratic trajectory in the long term. However, such developments in the energy market alone will not be able to change the situation, as there appear to exist a series of other geopolitical, sociological and colonial-historical factors impeding democracy as well. The paper strongly believes and argues that when these factors and elements discussed in this presentation are taken into consideration, there will be less violence and upheavals in the region.


Bibliography
Allan, J, A. (1999). ‘The Nile basin:
Evolving approaches to Nile waters management’. SOAS Water Issues Group: Occasional paper 20.
Allan, T. (1999). ‘Israel and water in the framework of the Arab-Israeli conflict’.
SOAS Water Issue Group: Occasional paper 15.
Atwan, A, B. (2006). ‘The Secret History of Al-Qa`ida’:
 Abacus.
Anon. (2009). ’Israel rations Palestinians to trickle over water’.
 Amnesty International
Baird, R. and Migiro, K. and Pentleton, A. and Farrant, A. (2007).
‘Human Tide: Climate Change: Outlook bleak’. Christian Aid.
Chomsky, N. (2003). ‘Middle East Illusions’. Rowman & Littlefield
          Publishers Inc.

Lanham. Boulder. New York. Oxford.
Fawcett, L. (2005). ‘International Relations of the Middle East’:
Oxford university press.
Flint, J. and Waal, A, D. (2008). ‘Darfur:
 A New History of Long War’. Zed books: London. New York.
Hovsepian, N. (2007). ‘The War on Lebanon: A Reader’. Arris books.
[Assessed, 10/5/18]

Jagerskog, A. (2002). ‘The Sanctioned Discourse:
A crucial factor for understanding water policy in the Jordan River basin’. Department for water and environmental studies, Linkoping University: Occasional paper 41.
Jobson, S. (2003). ‘Water of strife:
The geopolitics of water in the Euphtates-Tigris and Jordan river basins’. The Royal Institute of International Affairs.
Lssar, A. (1998). ‘The Water as a Parable’. Ha aretz.
Lssar, A, S. (2000). ‘The Water Resources of Israel:
Past, Present, and Future: A comprehensive outline’. The Palestinian Centre for Regional Studies.
Mearsheimer, J. (1995). ‘The False promise of international institutions’
          International
 Security 19(3).
Milton-Edwards, B. (2007). ‘Contemporary Politics in the Middle East’.
Polity.
Orr, J. (2009). ‘Iraq and Afghanistan: Dissent in the ranks’.
 Socialist Review. (340): 10-14.
Owen, R. (2004). ‘State, Power, and Politics in the making of Middle East’.
 Routledge: London. New York.